15

Seafield estate: economic aspects

15.1

The financial results of the drainage

To determine accurately in dollars and cents the total value to Seafield Estate of the subsoil drainage is a matter of considerable difficulty. Some items can be accurately assessed; on others it is difficult to put a figure. In order that the financial aspect of the work may be understood, it will be necessary to explain the labour problem of estates in this country.

15.2

Indian labour

In the F.M.S. planters desire to establish on their estates an Indian labour force. In part this is due to tradition; for the pioneer planters of Malaya came from Ceylon, where Indians, and more particularly Tamils from Southern India, were employed on the coffee and tea estates. The habits and customs of Tamils were understood, their language spoken by the planters; so it was natural that when coming to Malaya, where no indigenous labour was available, and some labour foreign to the country must be introduced, Tamils were selected. As a labourer the Tamil is quiet and reliable when justly treated; and from a few hundreds, the Tamil population has increased to tens of thousands.

To the Indian coolie, who comes here, the F.M.S. is an El Dorado in comparison with his native country; there he belongs to the lowest castes or “depressed” classes. In years of a “bad monsoon” and famine, starvation is his lot; years of prosperity give him a bare living. He comes to this country, as a rule, in poor physical condition, penniless, and in rags. A year on a healthy estate, with good wages and good food, improves him and his children beyond recognition. Not only is he well covered with clothes and flesh, and looks healthy; but he becomes relatively wealthy. Until last year he could live well on less than half his earnings, and the balance he could remit to his relatives in India at such a favourable rate of exchange that it often amounted in India to as much in rupees as he could have earned had he remained there. Through the Post Office are sent large sums annually; and even larger amounts are carried over personally. The immigration figures show that the coolie usually returns to India in two years; that means he has saved enough to do so. The employment of Indian labour at the wages earned on estates is, therefore, advantageous both to the Indian and the estate.

The system by which he is introduced to the country is comparatively simple. Some coolie on an estate in Malaya has friends or relatives in India who, he thinks, would come to the estate; so he is given a “licence” to “recruit” by the Labour Department—a department of Government which concerns itself with the welfare of the labourer. Armed with the “recruiting licence” the coolie visits his village, and if successful, brings over a few other coolies. These coolies receive a free passage from a fund raised by assessing all employers of Indian labour, and arrive on the estate free from debt. There is no “indentured labour” in British Malaya; no coolie may sign a contract to labour; he is at liberty to leave on giving a month’s notice, or at once on giving a month’s pay; in practice, as I have said before, he often leaves without giving either.

By law he must be provided with free housing accommodation, free medical and hospital treatment; and regulations of many kinds for his welfare are strictly enforced by the department referred to above. Where the death rate of an estate is high, the employer may be prohibited from employing Indian labour. In the early years of the industry, this rule was not strictly adhered to; for malaria and ill-health were regarded as inevitable in the opening of a new country and as a passing phase. But as the causes of ill-health have come to be better understood, and its prevention placed on a practical footing, the regulations are now very strictly interpreted and enforced.

So Indian labour is preferred because the coolie and his language are understood by planters, and because it is reliable when healthy. At the same time, there is considerable expense in recruiting it, in transporting it from India, and for medical treatment on the estate, especially when the estate is unhealthy. Indeed, if the estate be very malarious, the Indian requires higher wages, does poor work, is an indifferent, undesirable labourer, and ceases to be an asset.

Where an estate is very malarious, and the death rate is high, the Indian Government prohibits the employment of the Indian labourer.

15.3

Chinese labour

His place is taken by the Chinese, to whom Malaya owes so much. Long before the British administration was established in these parts, Chinese were working the rich tin land of the Peninsula. They come from a land where the seasonal variations give a period of comparatively, if not absolutely, cold weather, and are a virile race, full of enterprise and energy, well able to hold their own against any other race in the East; and probably, for that matter, against many in the West. Patient and efficient labourers; yet, for the European, difficult to work. This arises mainly from the fact that the language presents an almost insuperable obstacle to direct communication between the labourer and his Western employer.

Language!—it would be more correct to say languages. Although there is one ideographic writing common to the Chinese Empire, the dialects differ so much that Chinese from the several provinces cannot understand each other. In Malaya, the labourers speak many dialects; each one of which requires several years of study before even a smattering is acquired by the average European; and until the European changes his mental equipment or the Chinese his language, there is little chance of direct communication between the planter and the labourer. The difficulty is overcome by the planter engaging and supervising his labour through a “contractor,” a Chinese who speaks either English or Malay—the lingua franca of the Archipelago. Through him the employer arranges the terms of the contract; to him the planter gives directions; and he is held responsible for the proper execution of the work.

On an unhealthy estate, Chinese, like Indians, suffer from malaria and its accompanying diseases. He has no natural immunity. On occasions I have seen him as badly stricken by the disease as Indians; Port Swettenham in 1901 is an example. Chinese have little faith in Western medicine, and do not usually seek admission to an estate hospital. When ill, the coolie prefers to leave the estate and go to his friends elsewhere. There he is treated according to “Chinese fashion”: when well, he returns to the estate; if he dies, his friends bury him, and the estate manager probably hears nothing of it. Leaving the estate gives him a better chance of recovery than if he remained there subject to constant reinfection; and we find that a large percentage of Chinese on unhealthy estates have enlarged spleen, showing they have recently acquired or are acquiring a natural immunity. Two other things are in his favour: he believes in the mosquito net—practically every coolie uses one; and he feeds himself much better than the Indian. So it comes about that Chinese live and work on places where Indians die off rapidly and where the planter’s hope of establishing an Indian labour force—

Like Snow upon the Desert’s dusty Face,
Lighting a little hour or two—is gone.

If a Chinese coolie takes the risk of an unhealthy estate, he expects to be well paid for it. He is no philanthropist; on the contrary, he is fully convinced that the labourer is worthy of his hire—and sees that he gets it. Centuries of oppression in the Flowery Land have taught him the art of combination. His Societies and Guilds—practically every Chinese of the lower classes belongs to one—are so highly organised that a Western Trade Union could teach him nothing; and probably could learn a good deal. He is, therefore, practically in a position to make his own terms; and they are a long way above what the Tamil considers affluence, and flocks from India to obtain. In short, while with Tamil labour it costs on an average about 7 cents a pound to tap and collect rubber, Chinese tapping costs 14 cents. So Tamil labour saves, say, 7 cents a pound, and on a crop of 1,000,000 pounds in a year, the gross saving is from $70,000. This places a high premium on health; and, apart from any other consideration, has been a material stimulus to estate sanitation.

15.3.1

Bark renewal

I have said that the Chinese are “patient and efficient labourers.” Unfortunately this is often not true; and particularly when labour is scarce. Good Tamil or Chinese tappers do not remove more than one inch of bark each month, sometimes less. Rubber latex comes from the bark, which thus forms the capital of the estate. The renewal of bark requires time, and systems of tapping are arranged so as to give four or six years’ renewal, before the same part of the tree trunk is tapped again. Bad or careless tappers not only remove two or more inches of bark each month, but cut so deeply that the cambium is wounded; scars form in the new bark; where there are many scars, tapping over the renewed bark may become almost impossible.

There are widespread complaints from estates compelled to employ Chinese of the quantity of bark used and wounds made, and of the inability of the management to effect improvement as long as the only labour possible is Chinese; and there is a shortage even of that. It will be apparent from this that the cost to an estate of Chinese tapping is not merely the 7 or 8 cents a pound that it is over the Tamil cost; the loss of double the amount of bark is of even more consequence, since it may throw an area out of tapping for several years.

15.4

Advantages and disadvantages of Tamil labour

Tamil labour, however, is not without certain disadvantages which must be set against the cheap cost of tapping.

As far as Seafield Estate is concerned, the high death rate would have led to an order prohibiting the employment of Indians; even had some Indian labour been allowed, it would probably not have been sufficient in numbers, or reliable enough in “out-turn,” to tap the trees; all tapping would have been done by Chinese.

It is now time to detail, if not to assess, the value of the items in the account, and I will begin with the disadvantages.

  1. Indian labour has involved heavier medical charges. In 1919 these were $15,061.
  2. The total capital cost of the pipe drainage, 1911-1918, was $68,243.
  3. The upkeep of ravines, including oiling in 1919, was $11,013.
  4. To lay the system many rubber trees were cut out, reducing the rubber crop; this would probably have been an annually diminishing amount, as some of the ravines would probably have become silted up, and the trees would have died out.
  5. Cost of recruiting Indian labour.
  6. Assessment on Indian labour.
  7. Loss on selling rice below cost price.
  8. Loss on Exchange—remitting money to India above the market rate.
15.4.1

Advantages

  1. The improved health of the Europeans has
    1. reduced their hospital charges;
    2. reduced the sick leave;
    3. improved the supervision of work, particularly of the conservation of the bark—an important item.
  2. Abolished the cost of upkeep of open drains in the ravines—a considerable item on account of silting.
  3. Reduced the cost of tapping by the gradual substitution of Tamil for Chinese labour.
  4. The last of the Chinese left in November 1919; but subsequent to 1914, when the percentage of the total crop harvested by the Tamils had increased from 49 to 89, the improved health of the estate, and the competition from the Tamils, induced the Chinese to work at a rate considerably below the average for unhealthy estates. Before they left, the cost of Chinese tapping on Seafield was 8.31 cents per pound against an average of over 14 on unhealthy estates.
  5. There are certain advantages from the employment of Tamils in estate work generally, particularly in weeding. Under mature rubber, from four years old upwards, the shade is heavy and few weeds grow. But in younger rubber, weeding is probably the most important work. If land is weeded regularly every two or three weeks—that is, before the weeds can produce a crop of seed—the cost of weeding may be brought down to well under one dollar an acre per month; but if neglected for three months, it may cost seventy-five dollars or more an acre to clean up, and a heavy monthly expenditure afterwards, as I have explained in a previous chapter.32

The best, and in the end cheapest, weeding is done by hand; each weed being picked out of the ground and removed in a bag. This the Chinese will not do; the Tamils will. So during the years when the fields are young, a Tamil labour force is an asset of great value. Even when an estate is unhealthy and Chinese are employed for tapping, every endeavour is made to maintain a small gang of Tamils to weed the younger fields, and do similar estate work.

15.5

Cost of production of rubber

After many discussions with those familiar with the subject, it appeared that the only satisfactory way to estimate the value to Seafield Estate of a Tamil labour force would be to compare its f.o.b. cost of production with that of other estates employing Chinese labour, and to ascertain which was the cheaper. Inquiries were therefore made for an estate identical in acreage and yield with Seafield, but unhealthy and employing Chinese labour. As I was unsuccessful in finding one strictly comparable in all respects, I decided to ascertain the average cost on a number of estates employing Tamil labour, and to compare that figure with the average cost of estates with other labour. Messrs. Cumberbatch & Co., Ltd., Messrs. Harrison & Crossfield, Ltd., Messrs. Guthrie & Co., Ltd., Messrs. Barlow & Co., Messrs. A. C. Harper & Co., Ltd., Messrs. Barker & Co., Ltd., and the managers of several estates courteously supplied me with the details of estates with a total of over 71,000 acres in bearing, and from these I have worked out the average yield and cost. All are on hill land; they fall into three groups. For obvious reasons I am not permitted to give further details.

Group A, with 70% or more of the labour force Tamil. With one or two exceptions, all were intensely malarious, and but for the control of malaria would not now have a Tamil labour force. On several, further improvement in health is to be anticipated.

Group B have a mixed Tamil and Chinese labour force. On some there is a considerable expenditure on anti-malarial work, but a full Tamil labour force has not been built up. The health of this group generally is unsatisfactory, but there are exceptions.

Group C. Estates with 70% or more of the labour Chinese. Usually so unhealthy that Tamils cannot be employed. As a rule little is spent on anti-malarial work. Table 15.1 shows the total area in tapping in each group; the average yield per acre; and the average f.o.b. cost per pound in cents.

Table 15.1: Costs of rubber production on various hill estates with workforces that are mostly Tamil (Group A), mostly Chinese (Group C), or mixed (Group B)
  Group A Group B Group C
Acreage in bearing 29,068 22,120 20,043
Average yield (lbs./acre) 431.01 367.40 400.30
Average f.o.b. costs (cents/lb.) 28.25 37.45 36.03
15.5.1

Cost of production with a Tamil labour force

The average f.o.b. for Group C is 7.78 cents higher than for Group A, or roughly 30%. In 1919 the f.o.b. cost on Seafield was 24.17 cents, or 11.86 cents less than the average f.o.b. cost of Group C, the Chinese worked estates. The saving on the whole of the Seafield crop is, therefore, 11.86×1,147,553, or $136,099.

Assuming, however, that Seafield was an average estate in Group A with the average saving of 7.78 cents—then the gross saving still amounts to $89,279, or over £10,000 sterling. The capital cost of the subsoil drainage 1911-18 was $68,243—so that it was more than repaid in one year.

However we look at the matter, it would appear that the whole cost of the subsoil drainage was repaid and probably much more than repaid in the year 1919; and that the gain in previous years, while less in amount, can have been no mean sum. In other words, apart from the saving of human life and conservation of “bark”, the cost of the subsoil drainage has probably been repaid several times over in the past five years.

15.5.2

Cost of production with mixed labour forces

It is to be noted, and is significant, that on Estate No. 28, the cheapest producer in Class C (f.o.b., 29.78 cents), much is being spent on improving the health both by subsoil drainage and oiling; and its figure of costs may be compared with Estates No. 27 (f.o.b., 30.25 cents) and No. 22 (f.o.b., 26.60 cents) in Group B, on both of which also the health has been greatly improved, although labour forces exclusively Tamil have not yet been established. The higher cost of production of Group B as a whole, and its significant exceptions in comparison with Group C, would appear to indicate that there is a point in descending the scale of health, below which no advantage is to be gained from employing Tamils. It is, indeed, well recognised that, when an estate is unhealthy, Tamils cease to be an asset; and it is not uninteresting that these figures should bear out that opinion.

15.5.3

Cost of production with Chinese labour forces

Before passing, do not the figures for Estates No. 22, 27, and 28 suggest the thought that Chinese can work better and therefore cheaper where they are healthy; and that it would pay, even where a Tamil labour force is not aimed at, to make the estate healthy for the Chinese or whatever labour is employed? The Chinese, as a race, have keen business instincts. Where there is a choice, not even the most ignorant coolie will elect to go to an unhealthy estate in preference to a healthy one; nor will the headman or contractor under whom he works, for the latter has to live on the unhealthy estate with his coolies.

I have already mentioned that the Chinese have no natural immunity to malaria, although they do not die in numbers on the estates. They acquire in time a certain immunity; but during that period there is much sickness, many days when they do not work, many journeys into towns for treatment among their friends and according to their own methods. All this has to be paid for, if the coolie is to live; and he must be paid enough to live, for he is a necessity. It is, in fact, paid for by the higher wages he earns on the days he works. It may be taken as certain—even if the figures of the Estates No. 22, 27, and 28 do not prove it—that where an estate is healthy, Chinese can afford to, and do in fact, work at a cheaper rate than where the place is unhealthy.

From the employer’s point of view, whether the employer be European or Chinese, there are disadvantages from ill-health on an estate apart from the higher cost of production. It is a disadvantage to have a labour force constantly changing on account of ill-health. At times this leads to an actual shortage of even Chinese labour, which means a direct loss of crop; for the rubber not taken any one day is lost forever. It means, too, that a succession of tappers have to be trained, for tapping is skilled work; and in the training some damage to the bark, the real capital of the estate, is unavoidable. Finally, where, as in this country, labour is imported at great expense, it is simple common sense to keep that labour at the highest possible state of efficiency. Only a healthy coolie, whether Tamil or Chinese, is efficient; and the higher the efficiency the greater the production. So that, for Chinese no less than for Tamil labour, it would pay to control malaria, and money spent under medical charges would be well spent. I do not, of course, expect that the Chinese will patronise estate hospitals run on Western ideas; but I do think that money spent on subsoil drainage, oiling, removing coolie lines to healthy sites, and screened coolie lines, etc., to control malaria would improve the health and efficiency of the labour, and go far to make the Chinese dislike to hospitals a matter of indifference alike to the employer and employee—for there would be few sick.

15.6

The gross cost of disease

A startling figure is revealed when we consider the gross saving to the estates employing Tamil labour in Group A. The gross crop was 12,528,782 pounds; with the average saving of 7.78 cents a pound we got the sum of $974,737, or approximately £114,000 sterling in one year—no mean return on the amount spent to improve health.

If this be the saving to these few estates from which I have collected figures, what must be the total sum saved by all the estates in the Peninsula now able to employ Tamil labour forces because they are healthy? It must run into many millions sterling, even on the estates only the careers of which have been traced in these pages; and they are but a selection from the hundreds in the Peninsula.

Finally, we shall see later on, there is some reason to believe that 100,000 lives have been saved in Malaya in the last twenty years by sanitation, and principally through the elimination of malaria. If we estimate the wealth of a country by what its inhabitants produce, the saving of these lives and the value of their work lead our thoughts into figures that stagger us; but only do so, because we rarely count the cost of disease, and have not yet realised the value of medical research and the prevention of disease. As a nation, are we really practical?